domingo, 1 de outubro de 2017

The Growing Income Inequality




 

Prabhat Patnaik




THOMAS Piketty and Lucas Chancel have just written a paper as part of their work
for the World Inequality Report discussing the movement of income inequality in
India. And their conclusion is that the extent of income inequality in India at
present is greater than it has ever been at any time in the last one hundred
years.

Their estimates go back to 1922 when the Income Tax Act became operational in
India. The share of the top 1 per cent of the population in total income at that
date was around 13 per cent. It increased to 21 per cent by the late 1930s and
then fell to about 6 per cent by the early 1980s before rising to 22 per cent in
2014, the final year of their study.

What is striking about the paper’s finding is the almost exact synchrony between
the break in inequality trends and the transition from dirigisme to
neoliberalism. In the period between 1951 and 1980, the bottom 50 per cent of
the population captured 28 per cent of the increase in total income while the
top 0.1 per cent actually witnessed a decline in their income. In fact the
income of the bottom 50 per cent increased faster over this period than the
overall average. Between 1980 and 2014 however the top 0.1 per cent captured a
higher share of the increase in income (12 per cent) than the entire bottom 50
per cent (11 per cent).

To be sure, data on income inequality can always be questioned. For a start we
have no income surveys in the country; all we have are sample surveys relating
to consumption expenditure and getting from the distribution of consumption
expenditure to the distribution of income is problematical since we do not know
how savings, which constitute the difference between the two, are distributed.
Secondly, in all sample surveys, the top percentiles are always insufficiently
represented, precisely because they are so few in number. Statisticians
therefore make all kinds of assumptions about how income is distributed within
the top decile to arrive at the share of the top 1 per cent or the top 0.1 per
cent of the population. And these assumptions can always be questioned.

It is not surprising therefore that the Piketty-Chancel estimates too have been
questioned by some commentators. But no matter how one views their absolute
figures, the trends revealed by them can scarcely be questioned, since more or
less the same method of estimation is employed across time. And this trend is
entirely in conformity with what other researchers have been saying, and also
with what one would theoretically expect. Credit Suisse for instance provides
wealth distribution data. According to these data the top 1 per cent of
households in India currently owns more than half (57 per cent) of the total
wealth of all households, and wealth inequality in India has been rising
extremely rapidly, indeed more rapidly than even in the United States.

Wealth distribution is invariably more unequal than income distribution, because
the working class which has no wealth has nonetheless an income. Hence the
Piketty-Chancel figures for the share of the top 1 per cent in income are by no
means out of sync with the Credit Suisse figures about their share in total
wealth. (By the same logic however they seriously negate estimates that put the
share of wealth of the top 1 per cent at only 28 per cent, though even these
latter estimates recognize the significant increase in wealth inequality since
1991 when neoliberal reforms began and when the share of wealth of the top 1 per
cent was just 17 per cent according to them).

A measure of inequality that is often adopted is the Gini coefficient which
captures the distance between the actual distribution and an ideal distribution
characterised by absolute equality. The problem with the Gini coefficient
however is that by looking at the distribution as a whole it misses out on
questions like the shares of the top percentiles. For instance even when the
share of the top 1 per cent may be increasing, the Gini coefficient may show a
decline in inequality if some redistribution is occurring say from, say, the 4th
decile from below to the bottom decile, ie, from the “poor” to the “very poor”.
Piketty and Chancel accordingly do not use the Gini coefficient but look at the
shares of the top few percentiles, which is a much more useful measure
(especially if we are talking of economic power).

The Piketty-Chancel figures show that 1983-84 was the year of the lowest
income-share for the top 1 per cent, after which this share started rising. It
may be recalled that neoliberalism first made its appearance around that very
time and that the budget presented in 1985 by Vishwanath Pratap Singh, who was
then the finance minister in the Rajiv Gandhi government, contained significant
steps in this direction (against which in fact the Left parties had organised a
convention in New Delhi at that time). The association between growth in
inequality and the pursuit of neoliberalism is thus strikingly close. And not
surprisingly, such a growth in inequality has characterised almost every country
in the world in the period of “globalisation” which is characterised by the
almost universal pursuit of neoliberal policies under the diktat of
international finance capital.

The authors, both in the paper itself and also individually in interviews, give
a number of reasons why income inequality has increased in India in this period,
reasons having to do with the pursuit of neoliberalism. The decline in the
highest marginal income tax rate from 98 per cent to 30 per cent, the persisting
inequality in land ownership, and the lack of access to education and health by
the poor, are some of the points raised by the authors.

All these are very important. But there is an additional factor that needs to be
mentioned here, namely the attack on petty production, including peasant
agriculture, that neoliberalism has brought in its wake. While an improvement in
the conditions of the peasantry does not necessarily benefit the agricultural
labourers automatically, a deterioration in their conditions invariably gets
“passed on” to the labourers. And what is more, since, in the event of such a
deterioration, destitute peasants seek employment in the urban economy, where
very few additional jobs are being created, they tend to swell the reserve army
of labour which also affects the wages of the urban workers and hence the
overall urban income distribution.

In other words, as rural India has on average a lower income than urban India,
any widening of the rural-urban difference has the effect, other things being
equal, of widening overall income inequality (by the Piketty-Chancel measure).
But it also has the additional effect of widening the income inequality within
the urban sector itself. It does this via a swelling of the reserve army of
labour in the urban economy through the immigration of destitute peasants into
it. For both these reasons, the assault on petty production launched by
neoliberalism constitutes an important factor behind the growth of income
inequality.

The case of China, where, according to these authors, income inequality was
rising rapidly earlier but got reversed in the current century is instructive in
this context. To be sure, there are basic differences between the Indian and the
Chinese economies; but an important proximate factor behind the reversal of the
growing inequality in China was the policy adopted by the Chinese Communist
Party under the slogan “Towards a Socialist Countryside”. This policy checked
and reversed some of the encroachments on peasant agriculture that the attempt
to industrialise through a relentless export drive had entailed.

The introduction of a wealth tax (which, amazingly, India does not have), the
increase in income tax rates upon the rich, the provision of quality education
and health services to all under the aegis of the State, and of course land
redistribution, are undoubtedly some of the steps that must be taken to reverse
the growing income inequalities; and these entail a jettisoning of
neoliberalism. But even while recognising this, we must also recognise, which
the authors do not do explicitly, that neoliberalism is not just a policy of
choice that can be given up at will. It corresponds to a stage of capitalism
where international finance capital has acquired hegemony; overcoming
neoliberalism therefore requires a class struggle against this hegemony through
a wide mobilisation of workers and peasants.

The authors however rightly take on the apologists of neoliberalism who argue
that such a growth in income inequality is essential for achieving the high GDP
growth that has actually occurred in countries like India. This is absurd, since
the highest rate of income growth that has ever occurred in world capitalism was
experienced in the post-war period, during the so-called “Golden Age of
Capitalism”, when income inequality actually was declining the world over. This
decline in income inequality to be sure was not because of the operation of
capitalism but because of the concessions that capitalism had been forced to
make in the face of the looming socialist threat; but it shows that the argument
that growing income inequality is essential for higher growth is a complete
non-sequitur.     


In
PEOPLES DEMOCRACY
http://peoplesdemocracy.in/2017/1001_pd/growing-income-inequality
OCTOBER 1, 2017

Nenhum comentário:

Postar um comentário